The Design of Staged Contracting

نویسندگان

  • Albert Choi
  • George Triantis
چکیده

In negotiating complex business transactions, parties decide whether, when and how to invite legal enforcement of the rules that govern their relationships, particularly in their use of intermediate agreements that reflect some agreement on a number of provisions but contemplate further negotiation (variously labelled memorandum of understanding, agreement in principle, letter of intent, term sheet). Under the common law of most U.S. jurisdictions, the parties have an intermediate option between enforcement and no-enforcement of such intermediate agreements: a duty to bargain or negotiate in good faith or with best efforts. Law firms warn their clients about the risk of inadvertently bringing on this type of enforcement but with care, this risk is small. Rather, the parties are often unclear about the freedom they prefer for themselves or their counterparties to deviate from the terms of their intermediate agreements. They expect these terms to be sticky to some degree, but do not think through how much and by what means to achieve this. Judges and commentators identify the protection of specific investments as the principal goal of the commitment to bargain or negotiate. We suggest, however, that the benefit of the flexible standard of good faith or best efforts comes more broadly from mid-stream regulation of the negotiation process. The parties need flexibility in optimizing their deal, while also efficiently constraining value-claiming behavior and allocating exogenous risks during their negotiations. Building on our earlier work on strategic ambiguity, we also show that concerns about the uncertainty of such flexible standards can be addressed. * University of Virginia Law School and Stanford Law School, respectively. Acknowledgements to be added. Comments are welcome to [email protected] and [email protected]. Staged Contracting Version: April 3, 2017 Choi and Triantis Preliminary and Incomplete Page 2 of 26 Introduction Contract formation in commercial transactions can be a time-consuming and complex process involving multiple stages and players, and significant investments in expertise and information. In the design of the process, the parties face a core decision of whether—how much and in what respects—to invite legal enforcement of the rules that govern their relationships, and when to do so. Complex commercial negotiations are typically sequenced, with a subset of issues being addressed at each stage and by numerous agents with different expertise. The parties frequently enter into intermediate agreements—labelled memoranda of understanding, agreement in principle, letter of intent, term sheet—that reflect some agreement on a number of provisions but contemplate further negotiation of remaining terms, as well as subsequent approvals and formalization of their contract. An important part of designing the negotiation agenda should be the determination of the nature and degree of legal enforcement at this intermediate stage. This question seems essential to the broader decision as to why and how to divide the negotiations into stages. Commercial actors often do not think through this part of the negotiation agenda, and consequently (consciously or not) leave it to the courts ex post to determine the degree and nature of enforcement that they implicitly intended or would have intended if they had thought about it. Far from giving negotiating parties clear default rules to accept or opt out of, the law remains vague and in flux, even in the business-savvy jurisdictions of New York and Delaware. 1 Law firm client letters and surveys of commercial parties reflect confusion about the legal significance of intermediate agreements. Unless parties explicitly address the impact of their intermediate agreement, they face a risk of legal sanction for failure to complete their negotiations. 2 Law firms warn their clients about this risk and caution them to express clearly their intentions. With care, the legal risk is low. Yet, it appears that the parties are often unclear about the freedom they prefer for themselves or their counterparties to deviate from the terms of their intermediate agreements. They expect these terms to be sticky to some degree, but do not think through how much and by what means to achieve this. If a court finds that the parties intended to create a binding contract irrespective of further negotiations, then the court would likely fill in the gaps that the parties left for future negotiation with legal default provisions and award the usual measure of expectation damages. Short of such full enforcement, a court may find instead that the parties promised each other to continue negotiating up to some standard, such as good faith or best efforts, and most jurisdictions enforce this promise. The parties may have expressly agreed to do so in their intermediate agreement or the court may otherwise find manifestations of such intent in the language of the document and surrounding context. This raises three fundamental questions at this intermediate level of enforcement. First, how do the courts find the requisite intent for a good faith duty to negotiate, including the weight they give to the presence or absence of an express promise? Second, when 1 See, e.g., E. Allan Farnsworth, Precontractual Liability and Preliminary Agreements: Fair Dealing and Failed Negotiations, 87 Colum. L. Rev. 217, 259-60 (1987) (“[i]t would be difficult to find a less predictable area of contract law”). 2 Although this does not appear to be a deliberate judicial policy, it might be a plausible middle-ground approach between full and no enforcement. See infra notes – and accompanying text. Staged Contracting Version: April 3, 2017 Choi and Triantis Preliminary and Incomplete Page 3 of 26 negotiations break down and one party walks away, what constitutes bad faith? What effort or investment in negotiations is expected from each party? Is one party’s insistence on terms that deviate from the intermediate document’s provisions bad faith? When do changed circumstances or new information justify a party from terminating negotiations? Third, what is the appropriate remedy for the breach of the good faith duty? Reliance damages are the most common remedy, but injunctive and expectation remedies have been mentioned in narrow set of circumstances. A couple of courts, notably and recently the Delaware Supreme Court in SIGA Technologies v. PharmAthene, 3 have held that expectation damages might be awarded when there is sufficient evidence to determine the agreement that would have been entered into but for the breach. As with most contract law doctrine, the judicial approach is to find manifestation of the parties’ intent. Given the fact that intent is often unclear, it is worthwhile to identify and examine the factors that guide parties in the sequencing of negotiations, their memorialization of earlier stages, the constraints they choose to impose on later stages and the means by which those constraints will be enforced. Important scholarly contributions have been made to understanding this process in the fields of economics, law and negotiation, as well as by courts and practitioners, and we seek to build on them. There is a broad consensus on several points. First, the staging of negotiations is often necessary because of the complexity of the transactions. Second, a mid-stream memorialization of agreed-upon terms is valuable because it offers protection for the investments that parties make in the process that could leave them vulnerable to opportunistic hold-up in subsequent stages of negotiation. Third, this protection comes largely from non-legal constraints such as moral suasion, relational and reputational sanctions. Fourth, there is general consensus that parties should be able to opt into regulation of their negotiation through contracts to negotiate in good faith or with best efforts. 4 The law invites the parties to contract for legal enforcement, and it is desirable to give them an option of a middle-ground between no enforcement and full contract enforcement. Legal scholarship has identified a variety of legal approaches that could protect the reasonable reliance investment of the parties: from a simple implied promise to pay the reasonable reliance to a more complicated standard governing negotiations. 5 This essay suggests several other factors beyond encouraging specific investment and preventing hold-up that could motivate intermediate agreements. First, we suggest that this agreement is a tool for regulating other aspects of the negotiation process by discouraging inefficient value-claiming behavior (in addition to encouraging value creating investment). It is noteworthy in this respect that express promises to negotiate in good faith or use best efforts to negotiate, are often seen in agreements side-by-side with exclusivity promises not to shop an offer or negotiate with any other prospective party before a deadline. Second, a legal standard such as good faith or best efforts is useful to preserve flexibility to adjust to new information and changes in circumstances that alter the optimal deal terms or render the deal inefficient. Third, 3 SIGA Technologies, Inc. v. PharmAthene, Inc., 132 A.3d 1108 (S.C.Del. 2015). 4 E.g., Farnsworth, supra note --; Charles L. Knapp, Enforcing the Contract to Bargain, 44 N.Y.U.L.Rev. 673 (1969) (arguing in favor of a duty to bargain in order to protect reliance); Leon E. Trakman & Kunal Sharma, The Binding Force of Agreements to Negotiate in Good Faith, 73 Cambridge L.J. 598 (2014) (criticizing English courts’ reluctance to enforce agreements to negotiate in good faith). 5 A handful are described infra notes – and accompanying text. Staged Contracting Version: April 3, 2017 Choi and Triantis Preliminary and Incomplete Page 4 of 26 the intermediate agreement can also be a mechanism by which the parties can efficiently allocate some risks of changed circumstances that would affect the distribution of surplus from the deal. We argue that a contextual standard—whether good faith or reasonable efforts—is wellsuited to address this multi-faceted regulation of the negotiation process that parties often wish to invoke. Drawing from prior work on how parties can exploit the benefits of standards and avoid the potential costs of litigation and judicial error, we respond to the concerns of lawyers and scholars about the use of vague standards. The paper is organized as follows. Part I summarizes the relevant common law and judicial policy. As applied by the courts, good faith in negotiations is a standard that is focused on protecting specific investments and imposes some duty of fidelity to the terms settled in the intermediate agreement. Aside of these general observations, there is a widely held view that the judicial approach remains uneven and sometimes incoherent. Part II provides guidelines for the parties design of staged contracting, as well as their use of formal intermediate agreements to give some degree of stability to the terms settled in the early stage and regulate the remainder of their negotiation process. Part III describes the benefit of legal standards such as good faith or best efforts to support the parties’ objectives in staged negotiations. A legal standard is likely to yield superior results to either a regime of full contract enforcement or no legal enforcement. The Appendix demonstrates the advantage of a duty to negotiate in good faith for both (ex ante) efficient investment and (ex post) efficient contract terms. I. The Modern Law of Preliminary Agreements The modern law in most U.S. jurisdictions is based on a taxonomy of three types of agreements. The first is an agreement to agree which reflects an insufficient meeting of the minds and is not legally enforceable. The second is an agreement with open terms to which the parties intend to be bound, even if the parties contemplate an unrealized formalization of the agreement. This agreement is enforceable and the courts will fill in the missing terms, even price. 6 The third is a contract to negotiate (which is alternatively referred to as a contract to bargain or a type II agreement) in which the parties agree to a course of conduct during negotiations, usually by invoking a standard such as good faith or best (or reasonable) efforts. 7 In addressing these intermediate agreements—whether labelled as MOUs, LOIs, term sheets, or agreements in principle—courts and scholars have gravitated to the middle ground between full and no contract enforcement. 8 Most have converged on a duty to negotiate in good faith 9 but, in 6 See, e.g., Brown v. Cara, 420 F.3d 148 (2d Cir. 2005); Lippert v. Windsortech, Inc., 865 A.2d 1282 (Del. Ch. 2004). If there are open terms, the court can fill the gaps. See, e.g., Vsoske v. Barwick, 404 F.2d 495 (2d Cir. 1968); Berg Agency v. Sleepworld-Willingboro, 136 N.J. Super. 369 (1975); Larwin-Southern California v. JGB Ent., 101 Cal. App. 3d 626 (1979); Arnold Palmer Golf Co. v. Fuqua Industries, Inc., 541 F. 2d 584 (6th Cir. 1978); and UCC 2-305 (price gap-filler). 7 Farnsworth, supra note --, at 253, 263. 8 This has been a movement in the U.S. away from the historical common law position that agreements to agree are not binding. Ridgeway v. Wharton, 10 Eng. Rep. 1287 (House of Lords 1857) is a classic statement that agreement to agree is not enforceable. For decades contract scholars have been calling for middle ground with good faith standard. E.g., Knapp, supra note --; Farnsworth, supra note --. The modern trend is described in Keystone Land & Dev. Co. v. Xerox Corp., 353 F.3d 1093, 1097 (9 th Cir. 2003) and Burbach Broad Co. of Del. v. Elkins Radio Corp., 278 F.3d 401, 408-9 (4 th Cir. 2002). 9 E.g., Teachers Ins. & Annuity Assoc. of Am. v. Tribune Co., 670 F. Supp. 491 (S.D.N.Y. 1987); Brown v. Cara, 420 F. 3d 148 (2d Cir. 2005)(NY law); Venture Assocs. Corp. v. Zenith Data Sys. Corp., 96 F.3d 275 (7th Cir. 1996) Staged Contracting Version: April 3, 2017 Choi and Triantis Preliminary and Incomplete Page 5 of 26 contrast to some civil law jurisdictions, this duty must be found in the objective intent of the parties to be bound rather than being triggered simply by the start of negotiations. 10 Allan Farnsworth explained the policy behind the absence of wholesale regulation of negotiation in the U.S. as follows: “The difficulty of determining a point in the negotiations at which the obligation of fair dealing arises would create uncertainty. An obligation of fair dealing might have an undesirable chilling effect, discouraging parties from entering into negotiations if chances of success were slight. The obligation might also have an undesirable accelerating effect, increasing the pressure on parties to bring negotiations to a final if hasty conclusion.” 11 These downsides—chilling and acceleration—are avoided when the parties themselves choose when to invite the court to police their negotiations. Most courts are inclined to enforce clear and express language agreeing to or disclaiming good faith duty. But, sometimes the language is ambiguous or rendered ambiguous by other evidence, including: (a) the parties’ intent as revealed in the language of the agreement; (b) the context of the negotiations; (c) the existence of open terms or lack of clarity, particularly essential, material or major terms; (d) the conduct of the parties, including partial performance; and (e) the customary use of formalities in this type of transaction. 12 Even if the parties express their intent to have no binding obligations, extrinsic statements (including internal communications within one party’s organization) or conduct may lead the fact finder to hold that the parties intended to have good faith duty. Given the highly fact-dependent nature of the inquiry and the immaturity of the good-faith doctrine in this area, commentators have noted that the case law is characterized by inconsistent results and lawyers warn clients about the consequent traps for the unwary in letters of intent and similar documents. Although courts are no strangers to standards of good faith or best efforts, commentators have noted that the content of this standard remains unclear. 13 One important factor seems to be fidelity to the terms settled in the intermediate agreement. For example, in Teachers Ins. & Annuity Assoc. of Am. v. Tribune Co. (S.D.N.Y. 1987), Judge Leval stated that “parties can bind themselves to a concededly incomplete agreement in the sense that they accept a mutual commitment to negotiate together in good faith in an effort to reach final agreement within the (Ill. law); Newharbor Partners v. F.D. Rich Co., 961 F.2d 294 (1 st Cir. 1992)(Rhode Island); Channel Home Ctrs. V. Grossman, 795 F.2d 291 (3d Cir. 1986)(Pa law); Copeland v. Basking Robbins, 117 Cal. Rptr. 2d 875 (Cal. Ct. App. 2002); SIGA Techs., Inc. v. PharmAthene, Inc., 67 A.3d 350 (Del. 2013); Logan v. D.W. Sivers Co., 169 P.3d 1255 (Or. 2007) (en banc). It seems that less than a dozen have yet to enforce agreements to negotiate. [List here] 10 The good faith and fair dealing in the UCC and Restatement Second does not extend to pre-contract negotiations. See infra note – and accompanying text. 11 E. Allan Farnsworth, CONTRACTS (4th Ed. 2004) §3.26 at 199. 12 See Teachers’ Ins. & Annuity, supra note—at --. 13 E.g., Farnsworth, supra note --; Ronald J. Gilson, Charles F. Sabel and Robert E. Scott, Braiding: The Interaction of Formal and Informal Contracting in Theory, Practice and Doctrine, 110 Colum. L. Rev. 1377, 1427 (2010)(“the courts’ experience so far provides little normative guidance concerning the breadth of the enforceable obligation”); Alan Schwartz and Robert E. Scott, Precontractual Liability and Preliminary Agreements, 120 Harv. L. Rev. 661, 675 (2007) (“This modern approach provides too little normative guidance.”) Staged Contracting Version: April 3, 2017 Choi and Triantis Preliminary and Incomplete Page 6 of 26 scope that has been settled in the preliminary agreement.” 14 Under this agreement, a party may demand that its counterparty “negotiate the open terms in good faith toward a final contract incorporating the agreed terms.” 15 Itek Corp. v. Chicago Aerial Indus. Inc. (Del. 1968 and applying Illinois law) is perhaps the opinion that initiated the trend toward judicial enforcement of contracts to negotiate. 16 In that case, the letter of intent stated that parties “shall make every reasonable effort to agree upon and have prepared as quickly as possible a contract providing for the foregoing purchase...embodying the above terms and such other terms and conditions as the parties shall agree upon.” 17 Intermediate agreements often reflect the parties’ intention to limit the freedom of the parties to depart from terms settled therein and the courts are willing to enforce this intent in their application of the good faith (or best efforts) standard. 18 The predominant policy goal, as stated in federal and state court opinions, is to protect and encourage efficient transaction-specific investments and minimize the risk of opportunistic hold-up behavior. An example is the statement in a recent First Circuit opinion that “modern transactions often involve significant up-front investments in deal structuring and due diligence and parties may wish to protect those investments in some measure...without such protection, a rapacious counter-party may attempt to take advantage of the other party’s sunk investment by trying to retool the deal at the last minute.” 19 Some reliance investment seems essential. Judicial enforcement of a contract to negotiate is unlikely—even in the face of bad faith—if there is no significant reliance in between the stages; these are likely to be treated as mere agreements to agree. 20 Nevertheless, there are divergent opinions about the role of legal enforcement in promoting reliance. Contrast, for example, the opinions of two judges who are also contract law scholars, Judge Posner and Judge Easterbrook. In justifying legal enforcement, Judge Posner wrote: 14 Supra note --, at 498. 15 Id. 16 248 A.2d 625 (Del. 1968). A third party bid higher and the seller terminated negotiations even though the buyer agreed to all additional terms proposed by the seller, including price adjustments and other concessions. 17 Id., at 627. 18 After the release of the Delaware Supreme Court’s opinion in SIGA, supra note --, lawyers at Fried Frank wrote “[t]he obligation of good faith would be breached by abandonment of negotiations, insistence on terms materially inconsistent with the LOI; breach would be more likely if there is evidence of regret, and less likely if there is a material disagreement over a term not in the LOI” Andrew J. Colosimo et. al., Practice Points for Term Sheets, Letters of Intent, and Undertakings to Negotiate in Good Faith—Based on Delaware Supreme Court’s SIGA Decision, Fried Frank Private Equity Briefing (Feb. 8, 2016), available at: http://www.friedfrank.com/siteFiles/Publications/FINALv8-2-8-2016Practice%20Points%20on%20Use%20of%20Term%20Sheets%20and%20Letters%20of%20Intent.pdf. Lawyers at Lincoln Gustafson wrote that the good faith obligation would be breached by “attempt[s] to change fundamental points of the deal in order to take advantage of changing external conditions and extract more favorable terms than were initially agreed upon in the letter of intent.” Patrick Klingborg, When a “Non-Binding” Letter of Intent Is Binding After All, Lincoln Gustafson & Cercos, LLP (Jun. 1, 2016), available at: http://www.lgclawoffice.com/when-a-non-binding-letter-of-intent-is-binding-after-all/. 19 E.g., Butler v. Balolia, 736 F.3d 609 (1st Cir. 2013). See Burbach Broadcasting Co. of Del. v. Elkins Radio Corp., supra note -(“many state courts have recognized the pragmatism and commercial necessity of recognizing such agreements”); Brown v. Cara, supra note --; Copeland v. Baskin Robbins, supra note --. 20 E.g., Burbach Broadcasting Co. of Del. v. Elkins Radio-Corp., supra note --; Skycom v. Telstar, 813 F.2d 810 (7th Cir. 1987)(raising concern about making transactions riskier without need to protect reliance). Staged Contracting Version: April 3, 2017 Choi and Triantis Preliminary and Incomplete Page 7 of 26 “[S]uppose the prospective buyer spends $100,000 on research, planning and consultants during the negotiation, money that will have bought nothing of value if the negotiation falls through, while the seller has spent nothing and at the end of the negotiations demands an extra $50,000, threatening to cancel the deal unless the buyer consents.” 21 In contrast, Judge Easterbrook held in another case that: “Empro [the buyer of business assets] claims that it is entitled at least to recover its ‘reliance expenditures,’ but the only expenditures it has identified are those normally associated with pre-contractual efforts: ... ‘negotiating with defendants, in investigating and reviewing defendants’ business, and in preparing to acquire defendants’ business’. Outlays of this sort cannot bind the other side any more than paying an expert to tell you whether the painting at the auction is a genuine Rembrandt compels the auctioneer to accept your bid”. 22 We return to two facets of this contrast in the analysis in Part II. In particular, it may reflect a different view of the well-known tradeoffs in contract theory between protecting investment and providing flexibility to reach efficient agreements. In addition, it suggests that there may not be a uniform approach to protecting all types of investment and that it is helpful to have a taxonomy. Given that the protection of specific investment motivates the arguments for contract to negotiate, reliance is the usual measure. 23 A few courts have indicated, however, that expectation damages may be appropriate in the rare case in which the plaintiff makes the case that good faith efforts would have led to an agreement and the terms of that hypothetical agreement are clear enough that damages could be calculated. 24 The Delaware Supreme Court’s opinion in SIGA Technologies, Inc. v. Pharmathene, Inc. 25 held that the trial court could award expectation damages if it found that the parties would have reached an agreement if negotiations were conducted in good faith. Nevertheless, consistent with the case law described above, the Delaware court seemed to require some reliance, reflecting that this continues to be the motivating concern. 26 II. Designing Staged Contracting 21 Venture Associates Corp., supra note – at 278. 22 Empro Manufacturing Co., Inc. v. Ball-Co Manufacturing, Inc., 870 F.2d 423, 426 (7 th Cir. 1989). 23 Farnsworth, CONTRACTS, supra note --, at --. 24 E.g., Venture Associates Corp., supra note – at 278 (“if the plaintiff can prove that had it not been for the defendant’s bad faith the parties would have made a final contract, then the loss of the benefit of the contract is a consequence of the defendant’s bad faith, and, provided that it is a foreseeable consequence, the defendant is liable for that loss – liable, that is, for the plaintiff’s consequential damages.”) 25 Supra note --. 26 The SIGA opinion triggered renewed calls for care in drafting intermediate agreements. Philip Richter, a partner at Fried Frank, advises being more explicit either deny any obligation to negotiate in good faith, or providing for reliance or some kind of liquidated damages in lieu of expectation. Philip Richter, Negotiation in Good Faith – SIGA v. PharmAthene, (Jan 27, 2016), available at https://corpgov.law.harvard.edu/2016/01/27/negotiation-in-goodfaith-siga-v-pharmathene/. Staged Contracting Version: April 3, 2017 Choi and Triantis Preliminary and Incomplete Page 8 of 26 Two challenges face commercial parties in designing staged contracting. The first is whether a court will accurately find manifest intent to create or disclaim a contract to negotiate. This challenge is the focus of lawyers’ advice to clients, but the easier of the two. The second is what effect do the parties wish to assign to their intermediate agreement? In many cases, the parties give this question insufficient consideration, and they are often confused or of two minds. They may want simply to bind their counterparty while preserving their own freedom to walk. Or, they would like some mutual constraint but are unsure about how much and how to combine legal with nonlegal means to achieve it. A. Why and How to Sequence Negotiations The negotiation agenda, including the sequencing of issues, can affect the deal outcome and indeed, may be the subject of bargaining over process. 27 In many cases, negotiations are sequenced and a subset of issues is addressed at each stage. If nothing else, sequencing is a response to cognitive barriers to negotiating all issues at once. There is a tradeoff between the benefit of being able to logroll across issues to exploit differences in preferences and endowments, and the cognitive load of doing so. 28 When deals are broken up into manageable parts, how the issues are divided and sequences is a distinct and important question. One approach is that of gradualism or incrementalism, under which easier issues are settled first in order to build trust and a positive atmosphere, to create momentum to face the more difficult issues in subsequent stages. 29 The terms that are more difficult to resolve are more likely to be the major terms that, in turn, courts are more likely to require in an enforceable contract to negotiate. 30 An alternative strategy moves in the opposite direction, tackling first the potential roadblocks associated with essential terms before time is spent on the easier matters. This seems to be more common sequence in business transactions. This sequencing is reinforced by the need for costly lawyers, accountants, architects and other experts. It makes sense to have the essential elements of the bargain reflect the prospect of a profitable transaction before these investments are incurred. Although the first stage addresses the major terms—such as what is 27 Game theorists have shown that the decision to negotiate issues simultaneously or sequentially is likely to have an effect on the probability of success and the negotiated outcome. See, e.g., Thomas C. Schelling, THE STRATEGY OF CONFLICT 31 (1960); Chaim Fershtman, The Importance of the Agenda in Bargaining, 2 Games & Econ. Behav. 224 (1990); Younghwan In and Roberto Serrano, Agenda Restrictions in Multi-issue Bargaining, 53 J. Econ. Behav. & Org. 385 (2004); P.V. Balakrishnan, Charles Patton, Phillip A. Lewis, Toward a Theory of Agenda Setting in Negotiations; Mehmet Bac and Horst Raff, Issue-by-Issue Negotiations: The Role of Information and Time Preference (1996) (noting, for example, that the American Automobile Association recommends buyers focus first on negotiating price of the car and defer discussing of financing, factory rebates, and the trade-inallowance). 28 Howard Raiffa, NEGOTIATION ANALYSIS: THE SCIENCE AND ART OF COLLABORATIVE DECISION MAKING -(2002). 29 This is a common approach in international negotiations or agreements in legislative law making [add cites]. It is less common but nevertheless occurs in business transactions as well. See Ben-Shahar, “Agreeing to Disagree”, supra note --, at 390 (“leaving issues that were difficult to resolve for future completion. In these situations, contractual incompleteness is neither a result of haste nor of unforeseeability, but rather a deliberate choice to temporarily disagree over some matters, to side-step difficult issues over which consensus could not be reached.”) 30 Supra note – and accompanying text. Staged Contracting Version: April 3, 2017 Choi and Triantis Preliminary and Incomplete Page 9 of 26 being sold and at what price—the second stage is not trivial. Even if the second stage consists of lawyers hammering out representations and warranties, covenants, closing conditions, remedies and termination rights, these can contribute significant value to the transaction. 31 The sequencing of the monetary price of a transaction is particularly interesting, especially to the degree that it is difficult to revise a settled price because of the enforcement discussed below. 32 Price is a unique deal term in two important respects. First, it is likely to be the most divisible consideration in a contract: it can be adjusted by dollars while a quality measure cannot. Second, it is typically the distributional term in the contract with the least impact on the contracting surplus. Although price terms are usually determined after the nonprice terms have been set, this is not always the case, especially when significant specific investments are called for during the negotiations. For example, in commercial loans, private equity investments, and corporate acquisitions, many terms are agreed upon after the price is settled: representations and warranties, covenants, termination rights, choice of law and forum, and so on. 33 In the first stage of negotiations, the parties agree to price and key nonprice provisions, often without their lawyers, and then turn over the second stage to their lawyers to work out these contractual details. These terms, though valuable, are usually settled without adjustment to price. This arrangement leads to a peculiar process in the second bargaining stage between lawyers in which the parties are limited to bartering non-price provisions. 34 Thus, the stickiness of price constrains the ability of the parties to maximize the efficiency of their contract design, particularly when the parties are not using standard or market terms. 35 B. Purpose of Intermediate Document Parties to complex transactions are likely to engage in back-and-forth proposals of deal terms and, at some point, to memorialize the settled terms for the benefit of future negotiations and communications with internal and external constituencies. One view held by deal lawyers is that intermediate agreements are “signposts—they mark a moment in the deal’s lifecycle when enough uncertainty and complexity has been resolved that the deal is likely to go forward...[They are] markers for the accumulation of deal momentum.” 36 Rather than being 31 Although the value that lawyers contribute is difficult to quantify, the fact that they can command significant hourly rates for work performed after intermediate documents suggests that the market values their contributions to contracts in the second stage. [add cites] 32 See Albert Choi and George Triantis, The Effect of Bargaining Power on Contract Design, 98 Va. L. Rev. 1665, 1690-6 (2012). 33 See., e.g., James C. Freund, ANATOMY OF A MERGER: STRATEGIES AND TECHNIQUES FOR NEGOTIATING CORPORATE ACQUISITIONS 53-60 (1975). 34 It is interesting in this respect to contrast two types of debt contracts that settle price early or late in the process. In a typical commercial bank loan, the parties first negotiate a term sheet that contains the maturity, interest rate and other fees, in addition to a handful of major terms. The interest rate is rarely changed subsequently during the negotiation of the covenants, etc. In contrast, in the sale of a bond or debenture, the covenants are settled before the price is determined. Given the advantages of the price term and constraints on nonprice bartering identified in the text, one might speculate that, all else equal, the design of bond covenants would be more efficient. One might also anticipate more innovation in the provisions of non-bank debt, where the market can reward valuable contract terms with a lower yield. 35 Moreover, it is generally perceived that the second round presents the opportunity for the party with the bargaining power to seize more rents because the price cannot be reopened. See Choi and Triantis, Bargaining Power on Contract Design, supra note --. 36 Cathy Hwang, Deal Momentum, U.C.L.A. L. Rev. (forthcoming). Staged Contracting Version: April 3, 2017 Choi and Triantis Preliminary and Incomplete Page 10 of 26 binding, their presence indicates that momentum has been achieved so that a completed deal is in prospect along the lines of the agreed upon terms. The parties use this information as a sign that they can proceed to incur negotiation costs. 37 Indeed, these intermediate documents serve as evidence and information to the deal team of lawyers, accountants, and other advisers, as well as lenders, investors and other third parties who will contribute to the project. 38 In this respect, commentators sometimes refer to these intermediate documents as mechanisms for “organizing” these third parties. 39 Of course, the signal of momentum is not a particularly reliable one in the economic sense, because it is relatively cheap (or even costless) to send unless there is some sanction, legal or nonlegal, on the party that deviates from the terms of the agreement, thereby rendering them “sticky” to some degree. C. Stickiness of Settled Terms in Intermediate Document 1. Efficient Flexibility Many, if not most, preliminary agreements are not intended to be fully enforceable because the parties contemplate another stage in negotiation. 40 The law regulates more closely the modification of a contract than the completion of staged negotiations, even under a contract to negotiate. 41 Given that the court’s decision to police negotiations is founded on the objective intent of the parties, it is worthwhile to consider how sticky the parties themselves would want the terms to be in the intermediate agreement and based on what factors. To motivate this analysis, consider first the various reasons that the parties would want to be free to walk away from negotiations. The parties would be constrained in their flexibility to adjust to new information or changes in circumstances. These new circumstances or information could impact the efficiency of the deal as a whole or the optimal transaction terms. The ability to avoid an inefficient transaction and to opt for terms that maximize the surplus in the event the transaction closes is extremely valuable, especially when the parties are not well informed at the time of the intermediate agreement and operate in volatile environment. To the extent that the settled terms are sticky, the ability to negotiate for the optimal remaining terms may be constrained by 37 See, e.g., ABA MODEL PURCHASE AGREEMENT WITH COMMENTARY, v 2, 107 (2001) (“to test the waters for the prospects of a definitive agreement before incurring the costs of negotiating a definitive agreement”). 38 Included in these third parties are regulators whose approvals are condition precedent to the closing of the deals and who need the time to review (e.g. antitrust review). See ABA MODEL ASSET PURCHASE AGREEMENT, v. 2. at 107. Regarding the agency problems associated with having lawyers and other experts negotiate the second stage, see Albert Choi and George Triantis, Multi-stage contracting in complex transactions (working paper February 2014). 39 See Ralph B. Lake, Letters of intent: A Comparative Examination under English, U.S., French and West German Law, 18 Geo. Wash. J. Int’l L. & Econ. 331, 332 (1984)(“bringing order to complexity”); ABA MODEL ASSET PURCHASE AGREEMENT, v. 2. at 107; Hwang, supra note --. 40 Eg., Hwang, supra note – (“most preliminary agreements in M&A deals are signed, but specifically designated to be non-binding”). Hwang also notes that “deals are sticky even though enforcement for breach is weak”). 41 Under the Uniform Commercial Code, an enforceable contract modification requires not only mutual assent but also good faith which, between merchants, includes observance of reasonable commercial standards of fair dealing in the trade. U.C.C. 2-209, ct 2. “The effective use of bad faith to escape performance on the original contract terms is barred, and the extortion of a ‘modification’ without legitimate commercial reason is ineffective as a violation of the duty of good faith. Nor can a mere technical consideration support a modification made in bad faith” Id. The common law rule, as reflected in section 89 of the Restatement (Second) of Contracts requires either fresh consideration or that the modification be fair and equitable in view of circumstances not anticipated by the parties when the contract was made. Staged Contracting Version: April 3, 2017 Choi and Triantis Preliminary and Incomplete Page 11 of 26 limitations in logrolling against the terms in stage 1. This ability should not be surrendered without very substantial benefit from imposing some weight on settled terms. This is likely to be the reason for the court’s reluctance to enforce contracts to negotiate without sufficient reliance investments. 42 The ability of the parties to agree on the optimal terms may be impeded by asymmetric information about the relevant parameters, such as the value of the term to one party and the cost to the other. In the Appendix, we present a model of such asymmetry in which a nonbinding intermediate agreement is more likely to lead to efficient terms than a fully binding one. 43 Furthermore, regulation of the bargaining process through a standard of good faith or best efforts may in fact improve on the efficiency, by policing the better informed party’s ability to extract rent from the less informed. We return to this benefit from a legal standard of good faith in Part III. 2. Efficient Stickiness—Encouraging Efficient Investment Although enforcement of preliminary terms may interfere with the ex post efficiency of a negotiated deal, the decision to sequence negotiations presumably requires that the first stage terms would have to be somewhat settled before beginning the second stage. Otherwise, how would you maintain the psychological benefits of a gradual compromise or the fragmentation of complex issues? What would be the value of addressing roadblocks first if they could reappear late in the negotiations? Moreover, parties would negotiate more seriously before the intermediate agreement if they knew that there would be a cost to renegotiating or walking away from its terms. At the same time, excessive stickiness would chill negotiations and defer the memorialization of negotiations. 44 Similarly, if the purpose of the memorialization of a term sheet is to commence discussions with a lender or other third party, this purpose would be also be undermined if the parties could later change the major terms. Of course, these benefits and the ones described below would need to be weighed against the benefits of flexibility discussed above: adjusting to new information and changed circumstances and logrolling between terms across the stages. While lawyers warn their clients against agreeing inadvertently to binding terms in the intermediate documents, it is clear that parties do contemplate some form of commitment. Commentators observe that parties tend not to depart from the terms in the intermediate agreement and that the second stage usually leads to completed contracts. 45 How the stickiness is achieved in a matter of some speculation but it is often phrased in non-legal terms. Frequently 42 Supra note—and accompanying text. 43 Compare Jason Scott Johnston, Default Rules/Mandatory Principles: A Game Theoretic Analysis of Good Faith and the Contract Modification Problem, 3 S. Cal. Interdisc. L.J. 337 (1993)(analyzing bargaining in the shadow of contractual entitlements and the law’s policing of good faith). 44 Ben-Shahar, “Agreeing to Disagree”: Filling Gaps in Deliberately Incomplete Contracts, 2004 Wis. L. Rev. 389, 404-5 (also noting in the context of negotiations between states, a bargaining norm of no-retraction from preliminary understandings). 45 E.g. “Dealmakers [that were interviewed] with a wide breadth of experience – at firms and in-house, working with repeat players and one-off deal parties, in private and public deals, in a variety of firms and cities, representing financing parties and strategic parties – report that preliminary agreements have exceptional binding power.” Hwang, supra note --, at f54. Staged Contracting Version: April 3, 2017 Choi and Triantis Preliminary and Incomplete Page 12 of 26 commentary suggests that parties use them to bind counterparties “morally,” “psychologically,” or “ethically.” 46 Of course, some business entities hope to use intermediate agreements to bind their counterparty while retaining freedom for themselves to withdraw with impunity. 47 It is also possible that the reputation of lawyers provides the discipline discouraging the parties from walking or demanding unwarranted changes in settled terms. As indicated earlier, the dominant reason given for (partial) enforcement of intermediate agreements as contracts to negotiate is to protect and encourage specific investments that would increase the expected deal surplus or avoid an inefficient deal. Often, the investment contemplated by courts, scholars and lawyers, is the negotiating and contracting over the terms of the deal, and the retaining of experts to advise on performance (lenders, architects, etc.). 48 The classic concern of contract theory is that if price is negotiated after one party has made such reliance investment, the other party may engage in hold-up during negotiations of the price to deprive the former party of its investment. If the terms have not been settled, this hold-up hazard is unchecked and the parties may wish that the courts police it through a promise to negotiate in good faith. A related category of investment is in diligence to assess whether deal is efficient. This investment may occur before and after the intermediate agreement. In fact, from a survey of counsel to merger and acquisition deals, Cathy Hwang observes that although “[s]cholars assume that preliminary agreements are first steps...before investigation and before making relationshipspecific investments. In reality, parties sign preliminary agreements slightly later in the deal process, after most initial investigation is done.” 49 Their ability to continue conducting diligence can be enhanced in intermediate agreements by binding promises to provide one’s counterparty with access to records and related materials, share of expenses and adhere to non-disclosure requirements. In a different context, Schwartz and Scott examine incentives in “exploratory” preliminary agreements, under which the parties agree to make simultaneous investment in information that would indicate whether and which of a set of contemplated projects would be profitable to pursue. 50 For example, a seller would investigate its cost of delivering a good and 46 ABA MODEL ASSET PURCHASE AGREEMENT at 107 (“The parties may also feel morally, if not legally, obligated to key terms [in a letter of intent] if those terms are set down in writing”); Farnsworth, supra note -at 258; Knapp, supra note --, at 679 (business persons consider themselves bound, if not legally, at least morally or ethically); Freund, supra note – at – (“antirenegotiation insurance”); Lena G. Goldberg and Mary Beth Findlay, Just an MOU or a Real Deal? Harvard Business School Publishing Note 9-312-018 (2011) at p. 3 (“Unless there has been a material adverse change, it may be difficult, psychologically, to renegotiate terms that are expressly included in an MOU.)” 47 See Mark K. Johnson, Enforceability of Precontractual Agreements in Illinois: The need for a middle ground, 68 Chi.-Kent L. Rev. 939, 939 (1993). 48 Teachers’ Ins. & Annuity, supra note – at 14 : “without such an agreement, parties may spend enormous sums negotiating every detail of contract wording without knowledge whether they have an agreement, and if so, on what terms.” Hwang: “enforcing a preliminary agreement means that the parties can rely on their preliminary bargains as they engage in the costly process of solving for deal complexity.” In client letters, law firms advise clients to “determine whether they have a meeting of the minds on the material terms of a deal before proceeding with the more detailed, prolonged, and costly effort of definitive documentation”. Fried Frank, supra note --. And, to “make sure they are on the same page as to the significant points of a deal before they undertake the time and expense to prepare a detailed contract to express their complete agreement.” Lincoln Gustaffson, supra note --. 49 Supra note --, at --. 50 See Vladimir Smirnov & Andrew Wait, Holdup and Sequential Specific Investments, 35 RAND J. ECON. 386 (2004). Staged Contracting Version: April 3, 2017 Choi and Triantis Preliminary and Incomplete Page 13 of 26 the buyer would investigate the value it would receive, and the parties may agree that they would then share the acquired information to determine whether the transaction is efficient. Without enforcement of the promise to invest, each party has the incentive to cheat: to let the other party invest first and decide later whether to invest. The authors believe that the good faith duty can encourage investment by ordering the reneging party to pay the reasonable costs of the performing party’s preliminary investment. Scott and Schwartz remark that the predominant legal approach, via the contract to negotiate, “is deficient, however, because it is unnecessary to require the parties to bargain in good faith. As we show, efficiency would be enhanced if the law were simply to protect the promisee’s reliance interest.” In their analysis, they assume that the reliance expenditure is ultimately verifiable, as is its reasonableness, so the good faith standard is an unnecessarily indirect means to create the efficient investment incentive. 3. Efficient Stickiness—Discouraging Inefficient Investment Negotiation experts list several approaches to value-claiming: a strategy to capture a larger share of the surplus by changing the perceived bargaining range between the parties’ reservation prices. First, a party can improve its alternatives to the agreement (known as BATNA), raise its reservation price and thereby improve its share of the surplus. 51 It can do so by seeking and developing alternative parties. Of course, investing in alternatives can reveal a more efficient deal elsewhere; but the motivation of concern here is to improve bargaining power. Second, one party’s selfish interest is served by becoming better informed about its counterparty’s reservation price and changing its counterparty’s perception of its own. 52 Of course, the counterparty has the corresponding incentive to conceal that value. Expenditures incurred to conceal one’s own or reveal one’s counterparty’s reservation price do not contribute to efficiency, unless they produce information relevant to whether the deal and its terms are optimal. Third, a party may take actions to hurt the counterparty’s no-agreement alternative or BATNA and thereby change the bargaining range in the former party’s favor. The joint goal of deterring value-claiming investments is distinct from encouraging value-creating investments. As Schwartz and Scott point out, incentives for surplus-creating investments can be created by a simple promise to share expenses or reimburse if the deal falls through, because the party incurring the cost has the incentive to provide evidence that they were made and were reasonable. It is much more difficult to deter value-claiming investments because they are both difficult to observe and verify. It is not surprising, therefore, that intermediate agreements often have no-shop, no-talk or other restrictions on developing alternatives, alongside the contract to negotiate in good faith. 53 As is the case with many legal standards, the court’s investigation into the good faith or best efforts of each party can police value-claiming behavior not caught by these specific prohibitions. For example, it is easier to verify the seller’s marketing of an asset than the buyer’s search for alternative acquisitions. 51 David A. Lax and James K. Sebenius, THE MANAGER AS NEGOTIATOR: BARGAINING FOR COOPERATION AND COMPETITIVE GAIN 55, 251-2 (1986). 52 G. Richard Shell, BARGAINING FOR ADVANTAGE 104-5 (2006). 53 For example, in Channel Home Centers v. Grossman, 795 F.2d 291 (3d Cir. 1986), the letter of intent covered most of the significant shopping mall lease terms and provided that the prospective lessor would “withdraw the Store from the rental market and only negotiate... the leasing transaction to completion”. Staged Contracting Version: April 3, 2017 Choi and Triantis Preliminary and Incomplete Page 14 of 26 4. Risk allocation A final but important reason that parties may prefer stickiness in their intermediate agreement terms—also separate from reliance—is to manage the risk of changes in the environment. Risk allocation is a well-known, core function of contracts. Even if a deal is not completely negotiated, some risk allocation of changes in circumstances during the negotiation period is efficient and there may be gains to putting this allocation in place sooner rather than later. If the parties incorporate terms that assign such a risk, either explicitly or implicitly, the court should enforce that allocation. In this light, good faith may be breached when a party attempts to escape the adverse materialization of a risk allocated to it under the intermediate agreement, by breaking off negotiations or demanding an unreasonable modification of the settled terms. III. The Use of Legal Standards to Vindicate the Goals of Staged Contracting Intermediate agreements are best viewed as formal instruments that govern the parties’ negotiation process. Their focus goes beyond the protection of specific investments of various types. They create value by establishing parameters for negotiation to promote the following objectives discussed in the previous section: (a) encourage efficient investment, (b) preserve relative bargaining power by deterring value-claiming investment, (c) enforce the risk allocation desired by the parties during the negotiations and (d) allow flexibility to use new information and expertise to build surplus from the deal. 54 Under full contract enforcement, the court would fill the open terms in the intermediate agreement with the legal defaults and typically award expectation damages to the plaintiff. However, this would not balance well the multiple goals that often motivate the parties in the intermediate agreement and the optimal enforcement is something short of the full contract enforcement. While there is a broad consensus in favor of a middle-ground, there are a range of approaches suggested by legal scholar, many of which combine legal and non-legal enforcement. At one end of the spectrum, as mentioned above, Cathy Hwang observes that the terms of intermediate agreements are sticky even though enforcement by either courts or reputational sanctions is likely to be weak. She suggests that lawyers may be the gatekeepers whose reputations are harmed when a party walks away from such an agreement contrary to the parties’ expectations. As described in the previous Part, Alan Schwartz and Robert Scott advocate for protection of specific investment through reliance damages, particularly in the specific context they describe, in which parties commit to making simultaneous investments. Under their approach, the party who fails to make their investment must reimburse the nonbreacher’s investment costs. In a subsequent article, Ronald Gilson, Charles Sabel and Robert Scott advocate for this scheme of reliance damages as “low-powered” legal enforcement, which can 54 See Butler v. Balolia, supra note --, at – (“binding themselves sufficiently such that they feel comfortable investing resources into the deal, but without inextricably committing themselves to a transaction that is still inchoate. Contracts to negotiate can satisfy this need.”); Ben-Shahar, supra note --, at 407 (“The precontractual commitment enables a party to commit to a specific partner and a specific negotiation protocol without committing to specific terms.”) Staged Contracting Version: April 3, 2017 Choi and Triantis Preliminary and Incomplete Page 15 of 26 combine with extralegal forces to implement the desired degree of freedom from the substantive terms of the contemplated deal. 55 Jonathan Barnett describes an interesting alternative configuration of legal and extralegal discipline. He examines the context of Hollywood movie deals and suggests that parties are disciplined by a combination of industry norms and the possibility that a plaintiff would succeed in obtaining enforcement from a court. He refers to these deals as “soft contracts” that are possibly but not certainly subject to legal liability. Parties can achieve their preferred level of enforcement and, conversely, transactional flexibility by calibrating the level of formalization used to memorialize the terms, and therefore the probability that they will be legally binding. Barnett describes that “parties face a calculated tradeoff—with respect to each deal element, deal stage, and deal participant – that weighs the marginal transactional flexibility [from the ability to walk away] and cost savings from reduced formalization against the marginal increased risk of holdup and other forms of counterparty opportunism”. 56 Omri Ben-Shahar focuses on incomplete agreements where the parties deliberately leave terms to be agreed upon later. 57 Instead of having the court police the specific investments of the parties, he advances a novel proposal that the party seeking enforcement of a deliberately incomplete agreement would have an option to enforce the transaction under the agreed-upon terms supplemented by terms that are the most favorable (within reason) to the defendant. BenShahar argues that this facilitates sequential negotiations and deters unilateral retractions or threats to precontractual investments. 58 Although practitioners, courts and scholars are all aware of the existence of nonlegal sanctions that visit the party who unreasonably withdraws from negotiations or makes outlandish demands. Sometimes, these extralegal forces achieve the desirable combination of commitment and flexibility. For example, in his discussion of soft contracts between Hollywood movie studios and star actors, Jonathan Barnett reports that there are norms deterring the most egregious forms of hold-up that are available once a studio has begun filming with a star. He observes that “[i]n practice, nothing close to this extreme form of holdup behavior actually occurs: even in the absence of a signed deal, talent attorneys report that they renegotiate open terms following production but refrain from renegotiating the fixed compensation.” 59 This is consistent with the good faith negotiations that are sometimes required in intermediate commercial agreements which impede the renegotiation of settled terms but provide flexibility in the negotiation of open terms. In other contexts, however, lawyers and scholars acknowledge that nonlegal sanctions do not completely deter such behavior and might be paired with some degree of legal enforcement. Scott Baker and Albert Choi observe that many extralegal sanctions impose costs on both the party that metes the sanction and the one that receives it. 60 To impose a meaningful relational or 55 Gilson, Sabel and Scott, supra note --. 56 Id., at 644. 57 Ben-Shahar, supra note --. 58 Id., at 392. 59 Barnett, supra note – at 641. 60 Scott Baker and Albert Choi, Contracts Role in Relational Contract, 101 Va. L. Rev. 559 (2015). Staged Contracting Version: April 3, 2017 Choi and Triantis Preliminary and Incomplete Page 16 of 26 reputational sanction, the enforcer must forego a profitable transaction or relationship with the transgressor, with a corresponding loss in social welfare. In contrast, the outcome of legal enforcement is a payment (e.g. of reliance damages) between the parties, with some deadweight loss for litigation. The parties, ex ante, may prefer the latter system. In addition, in many contexts, the legal system is a reasonably effective producer of information about the conduct of the alleged bad actor, with access to different and sometimes superior information than the counterparty and to third parties in the reputational community. The fact finding of the courts may inform the discretion of these parties to impose nonlegal sanctions. The use of a standard—such as good faith or reasonable efforts—to police the negotiation process seems an appropriate mechanism for legal enforcement of intermediate agreements. We have identified several goals that the parties may seek to promote in regulating their negotiation process, beyond the protection of reasonable reliance investment. These require a highly contextual approach that befits a standard. Good faith and best efforts are familiar standards in contract and commercial law. Lawyers and scholars are often critical of vague standards that call for fact-specific determinations because they introduce the costs of unpredictability, judicial error and litigation cost. Noting that contracting parties regularly agree to standards of conduct when more precise rules are available, we have addressed these concerns in other work. In brief, the costs of litigation and judicial error are, of course, avoided when parties settle their dispute, as they often do. Moreover, they can be mitigated and a more efficient incentive can be implemented, when the standards are combined with contract provisions that calibrate litigation costs and liquidated damages for breach. Whether the parties adopt a negotiation standard of good faith or best efforts, the parties can realize the benefits of their contextual application while avoiding the downsides. 61 Regulating negotiations with a standard such as good faith promotes the various objectives of the party. In particular, the analysis in the Appendix herein demonstrates that the standard is superior to either of the alternatives of full enforcement or no enforcement. Full contract enforcement of intermediate agreements yields the worst incentives for either investment or contract term production; no enforcement is superior. The analysis shows that judicial enforcement of a duty to negotiate in good faith creates the optimal level of stickiness to promote both ex post flexibility and ex ante investment. Achieving optimal flexibility can coincide with achieving optimal investment. In fact, in our model, there is no tradeoff: the parties need to anticipate ex post efficiency (efficient flexibility) to be able to achieve ex ante efficiency (reliance investment). In the Appendix, a party invests in information that could indicate which of alternative provisions left to the second stage would be efficient. The analysis there conceptualizes bad faith behavior as a party attempting to renegotiate the terms of the agreement solely for the purpose of extracting more rent from the counter party even though the party has reason to know that the renegotiated term will not increase the surplus from trade. By imposing duty to negotiate in good faith, backed by court enforcement that is costly to obtain, the contracting parties can discourage such opportunistic behavior. Moreover, when the parties are reassured 61 In this sense we are allied with Barnett, supra note --, who similarly sees virtue in probabilistic enforcement; but we endorse the use of a substantive standards in the terms (good faith, best efforts) rather than the uncertainty from incomplete formalization of the deal. Staged Contracting Version: April 3, 2017 Choi and Triantis Preliminary and Incomplete Page 17 of 26 that opportunistic behavior is deterred, it is easier for them to modify the terms when they are, in fact, more efficient.

برای دانلود رایگان متن کامل این مقاله و بیش از 32 میلیون مقاله دیگر ابتدا ثبت نام کنید

ثبت نام

اگر عضو سایت هستید لطفا وارد حساب کاربری خود شوید

منابع مشابه

Contracting Out Non-State Providers to Provide Primary Healthcare Services in Tanzania: Perceptions of Stakeholders

Background In the attempt to move towards universal health coverage (UHC), many low- and middle-income countries (LMICs) are actively seeking to contract-out non-state providers (NSPs) to deliver health services to a specified population. Research on contracting-out has focused more on the impact of contracting-out than on the actual processes underlying the intervention and contextual factors ...

متن کامل

Optimisation of Healthcare Contracts: Tensions Between Standardisation and Innovation; Comment on “Competition in Healthcare: Good, Bad or Ugly?”

An important determinant of health system performance is contracting. Providers often respond to financial incentives, despite the ethical underpinnings of medicine, and payers can craft contracts to influence performance. Yet contracting is highly imperfect in both single-payer and multi-payer health systems. Arguably, in a competitive, multi-payer environment, contractual innovation may occur...

متن کامل

University and industry: From contracting relations to strategic partnerships; providing strategic role model in university-society relations

Establishing sustainable and effective interactions between university and society has always been a concern for higher education system. However, these interactions have always been challenged for various reasons. The reasons can be attributed to the type of attitudes toward the roles a university plays in interaction with industry, the lack of value-added strategic interactions with industry,...

متن کامل

Staged Financing in Venture Capital: Moral Hazard and Risks

This paper investigates staged ... nancing in an environment where an entrepreneur faces an imperfect capital market and an investor faces moral hazard and uncertainty. Staged ... nancing plays two roles in this model: to control risk and to mitigate moral hazard. Using parametric functions and comparing staged ... nancing with upfront ... nancing, we discover a few interesting properties of st...

متن کامل

Prospecting polymetallic mineralization in Ardestan area, Central Iran, using fractal modeling and staged factor analysis

The purpose of this study is to determine geochemical anomalies on lithogeochemical data from Ardestan area, Central Iran, using concentration-number (C-N) fractal modeling and staged factor analysis. Staged factor analysis is used to the recognition of genetic correlation and elimination of non-indicator elements in three steps. Factor scores of elements were calculated and geochemical data cl...

متن کامل

A Model for Sharing the Costs of Uncontrollable Risks among Contracting Parties

The allocation of risks among the contracting parties in a contract is an important decision affecting the project success. Some risks in a project are uncontrollable; these are imposed to a project by external factors. Since contracting parties can neither control nor affect the occurrence of such risks, their allocation to a party would be inequitable. Therefore the cost overrun related to un...

متن کامل

ذخیره در منابع من


  با ذخیره ی این منبع در منابع من، دسترسی به آن را برای استفاده های بعدی آسان تر کنید

عنوان ژورنال:

دوره   شماره 

صفحات  -

تاریخ انتشار 2017